Saturday, October 15, 2016
Weekly Indicators for October 10 - 14 at XE.com
- by New Deal democrat
My Weekly Indicator post is up at XE.com. Between energy, commodities, the US$, and mortgage applications, there has been a slight but noticeable darkening of the picture.
Friday, October 14, 2016
September retail sales: positive with one fly in the ointment
- by New Deal democrat
As you all probably already know, real retail sales is one of my favorite metrics. I haven't looked at it in a little while, so this morning's report is a good opportunity to catch up.
The below graph shows nominal (blue) and real (red) retail sales.
With a nice +0.6% increase in September, nominal retail sales are at another record. So long as consumer prices have not increased by more than 0.2% (we'll find out next week), real retail sales set another record as well.
Further, sales lead jobs. The direction of the YoY rate of change in retail sales tends to lead YoY payroll growth by 6 - 12 months. Here are the last 10 years ending August:
This argues that YoY job growth is likely to be stable to slightly decelerating in the next few months, a somewhat contrary signal to that given by the Labor Market Conditions Index released several days ago.
Finally, the one fly in the ointment is that, between anticipated inflation in September, plus normal population growth of about .075% per month, it is unlikely that real retail sales per capita will be better than flat compared with June and July:
Real retail sales per capita is a long leading indicator, and this suggests it will have made no improvement over the last 4 months.
Wednesday, October 12, 2016
JOLTS, Labor Market Conditions index consistent with late 2017 recession
- by New Deal demorat
I continue to be unimpressed with the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS), as showing post-mid cycle deceleration for over a year. I have found what I hope is a better way to present my argument, so that you can see why the report is less than heartening.
First, here is a comparison of job openings (blue), hires (red), and quits (green, right scale). Because there is only one compete past business cycle for comparison, lots of caution is required. But in that cycle, hires and quits peaked first, while openings continued to rise before turning down in the months just prior to the onset of the Great Recession:
Through today's report for August, 2016 looks very much like 2006, or even early 2007.
To better show you my concern, let's look at this same data as expressed in YoY% changes:
Although there's lots of noise in the squiggles, the pattern of maximum growth at mid cycle gradually declining under zero prior to the onset of the 2008 recession is evident. Here is a close-up of the years 2005-08 to show you the deceleration of quits and hires from their peaks in late 2005, and the flatness of hires before declining in the months just before the recession:
Now let's look at the same time frame up until this month's release:
You can see similar peaks of quits and hires in late 2014, and the general flatness in hires over the last year. The rates of YoY change are equivalent to those at the end of 2006.
If the same pattern as the last economic cycle were to hold for this one, JOLTS would show continued deceleration before rolling over into an actual recession about 12 months from now.
Meanwhile the LMCI has been slightly negative virtually all this year. As shown in the graph below, this is consistent with slowdowns (as in 1985 and 1995) as well as prior to recessions:
Still, the LMCI has not declined nearly as much as it typically has prior to most of the recessions in the last 50 years. At the same time, note that the LMCI does a pretty good job forecasting the direction of the YoY change in employment (red). So the YoY trend in the monthly jobs report is likely to continue to decelerate.
Still, the LMCI has not declined nearly as much as it typically has prior to most of the recessions in the last 50 years. At the same time, note that the LMCI does a pretty good job forecasting the direction of the YoY change in employment (red). So the YoY trend in the monthly jobs report is likely to continue to decelerate.
While I'm not forecasting any actual negative monthly job reports in the near future, the YoY payrolls graph still shows continued deceleration. Here is a bar graph of the monthly gain in jobs for the last 3 years, minus 150,000, better to show the deceleration from the peak of nearly 2 years ago:
The 4th quarter of last year showed job increases of over 250,000 per month. It is a virtual certainty that the job reports for this quarter are going to average much less.
In summary, both the LMCI and the JOLTS reports have been adding to the accumulating evidence that we are getting late in the expansion, if we only go by these two metrics, and we follow the 2001-07 template, a recession could begin within about 12 months. Which means that this month's housing data, as well as the long leading business profit and residential investment data in the first Q3 GDP estimate will take on added importance.
Tuesday, October 11, 2016
Does the recent stagnation in the unemployment rate mean we're DOOOMED?
- by New Deal democrat
The unemployment rate has varied between 4.7% and 5.1% over the last 12 months. Does that mean a recession is near, or even already here? I examine this at XE.com.
Monday, October 10, 2016
Five graphs for 2016: Q3 update
- by New Deal democrat
At the beginning of this year, I identified graphs of 5 aspects of the economy that most bore watching. Now that we are 3/4's through the year, let's take a look at each of them.
#5 The Yield Curve
The Fed attempted to embark on a tightening regimen last December. The question became, would the yield curve compress or, worse, invert, an inversion being a nearly infallible sign of a recession to come in about 12 months. It turned out that the weakness in the world economy plus Brexit caused a moderate compression just at the long end:
After the June Brexit vote, the 10 year treasury fell to all time lows (typically long rates only start to fall once the tightening cycle has caused the economy to weaken). Indeed, weakness in the economy has put the Fed back on hold all this year. The bottom line is that the yield curve is still quite positive when seen in a historical perspective.
#4 The trade weighted US$
Perhaps the biggest story of 2015 was the damage done by the 15%+ surge in the US$ that began in late 2014 -- which not only harmed exports, but pretty much cancelled out the positive effect on consumers' wallets by lower gas prices.
Here there has been a big change:
Against all currencies, the US$ has recently ben in the range of unchanged to +3% YoY - a more typical if still elevated range. Against major currencies, the US$ has actually declined YoY for most of this year.. This is good news.
Against all currencies, the US$ has recently ben in the range of unchanged to +3% YoY - a more typical if still elevated range. Against major currencies, the US$ has actually declined YoY for most of this year.. This is good news.
#3 The inventory to sales ratio
An elevated ratio of business inventories to sales means that businesses are overstocked. This has frequently but not always been associated with a recession. I have been using the wholesalers invenotry to sales ratio, since it has fewer secular issues. This ratio increased has fallen significantly since its high in January:
The good new is that this kind of fall tends to happen as a recession ends. the bad news is that it hasn' fallen more, telling us that the inducstrial economy is still weak.
The good new is that this kind of fall tends to happen as a recession ends. the bad news is that it hasn' fallen more, telling us that the inducstrial economy is still weak.
#2 Discouraged workers
While 2015 saw a big improvement in involuntary part time employment, this trend has completely stalled in the last 12 months:
We are still at least 1,500,000 above a "good" number. Worse, this kind of stall is something that we see as a cycle is approaching its peak.
We are still at least 1,500,000 above a "good" number. Worse, this kind of stall is something that we see as a cycle is approaching its peak.
#1 Underemployment and wages
The single worst part of this economic expansion has been its pathetic record for wage increases. Nominal YoY wage increases for nonsupervisory workers were generally about 4% in the 1990s, and even in the latter part of the early 2000s expansion. In this expansion, however, until recently nominal increases averaged a pitiful 2%, meaning that even a mild uptick in inflation is enough to cause a real decrease in middle and working class purchasing power.
There is increasing consensus that the primary reason for this miserable situation has been the persistent huge percentage of those who are either unemployed or underemployed, such as involuntary part time workers.
The single worst part of this economic expansion has been its pathetic record for wage increases. Nominal YoY wage increases for nonsupervisory workers were generally about 4% in the 1990s, and even in the latter part of the early 2000s expansion. In this expansion, however, until recently nominal increases averaged a pitiful 2%, meaning that even a mild uptick in inflation is enough to cause a real decrease in middle and working class purchasing power.
There is increasing consensus that the primary reason for this miserable situation has been the persistent huge percentage of those who are either unemployed or underemployed, such as involuntary part time workers.
This expanded "U6" unemployment rate ( minus 10%) is shown in blue in the graph below, toether with YoY nominal wage growth (minus 2%):
In the 1990s and 2000s, once the U6 underemployment rate fell under 10%, nominal wage growth started to accelerate. U6 has been under 10% for close to a year,, and there has been some mild improvement off the bottom. More than anything, the US needs real wage growth for labor, and the present nominal reading of 2.6% still isn't nearly good enough. With the expansion in deceleration mode well past mid-cycle, it is not clear at all how much further improvement we are going to get before the next recession hits.
In the 1990s and 2000s, once the U6 underemployment rate fell under 10%, nominal wage growth started to accelerate. U6 has been under 10% for close to a year,, and there has been some mild improvement off the bottom. More than anything, the US needs real wage growth for labor, and the present nominal reading of 2.6% still isn't nearly good enough. With the expansion in deceleration mode well past mid-cycle, it is not clear at all how much further improvement we are going to get before the next recession hits.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)